¿Se financió la defensa a costa del gasto social y la economía en el siglo XX? El dilema cañones versus mantequilla

  1. Jurado Sánchez, José
Revista:
Hacienda Pública Española / Review of Public Economics

ISSN: 0210-1173

Año de publicación: 2012

Número: 203

Páginas: 89-117

Tipo: Artículo

DOI: 10.7866/HPE-RPE.12.4.4 DIALNET GOOGLE SCHOLAR lock_openAcceso abierto editor

Otras publicaciones en: Hacienda Pública Española / Review of Public Economics

Resumen

Las interrelaciones entre el gasto militar y el civil y sus consecuencias económicas y sociales duranteel siglo XX han sido objeto de numerosas investigaciones desde hace varias décadas. En las publica-das hasta mediados del decenio de 1970 se defiende que el gasto social y la economía sufragaron la de-fensa, mientras que en la mayoría de las editadas después se sostiene que los cañones no se fabricarona costa de la mantequilla o no se hallan pruebas consistentes de lo contrario. Esta diversidad de resul-tados se debe a las diferentes teorías, metodologías y técnicas estadísticas utilizadas en la investigaciónde un asunto que sería de gran interés iniciar en España.

Referencias bibliográficas

  • Abelson, r. P. (1963), "A 'derivation' of richardson's equations", The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 7, 1: 13-15
  • Alexander, W. r. j. (1986), "The Impact of Defence Spending on Economic Growth: a Multisectorial Approach to Defence and Economic Growth with Evidence from Developed Economies", Defence Economics, 2, 1: 39-55.
  • Anderton, CH. H. (1990), "Teaching Arms-race Concepts in Intermediate Microeconomics", The Journal of Economic Education, 21, 2: 148-166.
  • Benoit, E. (1973), Defense and Economic Growth in Developing Countries, Lexinton, MA: D.C. Heath.
  • Berry, W. y Lowery, D. (1990), "An Alternative Approach to understanding Budgetary Tradeoffs", American Journal of Political Science, 34, 3: 671-705.
  • Cappelen, A.; Gleditsch, n. P. y Bjerkholt, o. (1984), "Military Spending and Economic Growth in the oECD Countries", Journal of Peace Research, 21, 4: 361-373.
  • Caputo, D. (1975), "new perspectives on the public policy implications of defense and welfare expenditures", Policy Science, 6: 423-446.
  • Clayton, j. L. (1976), "The Fiscal Limits of the Warfare-Welfare State: Defense and Welfare Spending in the united States since 1900", Western Political Quaterly, 29, 3: 364-383.
  • Chan, S. (1985), "The Impact of Defense Spending on Economic Performance: A Survey of Evidence and Problems", Orbis, 29, 3: 403-434
  • Chan, S. (1987), "Military Expenditures and Economic Performance", in World Military Expenditures and Arms Transfers, 1986, Washington DC: u.S. Arms Control and Disarmament Agency.
  • DeGrasse, r. W., jr. (1983), Military Expansion, Economic Decline: The Impact of Military Spending on U.S. Economic Performance, new York: Council on Economic Priorities.
  • Denison, E. F. (1985), Trends in American Economic Growth, Washington DC: Brookings Institution.
  • Domke, W.; Eichenberg, r. y Kelleher, C. (1983), "The illusion of choice: defense and welfare in advanced industrial democracies, 1948-1978", American Political Science Review, 77, 1: 19-34.
  • Dudley, L. y Montmarquette, C. (1981), "The Demand for Military Expenditure: An International Comparison", Public Choice, 37, 1: 5-31.
  • Dunne, j. P. (1996), "Economic effects of military spending in developing countries: a survey", en n. P. Gleditsch et alii (eds.), The Peace Dividend, Amsterdam: north Holland: 439-464.
  • Dunne, j. P. y uye, M. (2009), "Military expenditure and development", en A. Tan (ed.), The Global Arms Trade, London: routledge: 293-305.
  • Gifford, B. (2006), "Why no Trade-off between 'Guns and Butter'? Armed Forces and Social Spending in the Advanced Industrial Democracies, 1960-1993", American Journal of Sociology, 112, 2: 473-509.
  • Hartley, K. y Sandler, T. (2001), The Economics of Defence, Cheltenham y northamptom: Elgar Publishing, 3 vols.
  • Hartman, S. W. (1973), "The Impact of Defense Expenditure on the Domestic American Economy, 1964-1972", Public Administration Review, 33: 379-390.
  • Harvey, A. C. (1981), The Econometric Analysis of Time Series, new York: Wiley.
  • Heo, u. (1999), The Political Economy of Defense Spending around the World, Lewiston, new York: Edwin Mellen.
  • Hibbs, D. A. (1974), "Problems of Statistical Estimation and Causal Inferences in Time-Series regression Models", en Sociological Methodology: 1973-1974.
  • Hollenhorst, j. y Ault, G. (1971), "An Alternative Answer to Who Pays for Defense", American Political Science Review, 65, 3: 760-763.
  • Huang, C. y Mintz, A (1990), "ridge regression analysis of the defense-growth tradeoff in the united States", Defence Economics, 2: 29-37.
  • Huisken, r. (1982), "Armaments and Development", in H. Tuomi y r. Vayrinen (eds.), Militarization and Arms Production, new York: St. Martin Press, 3-25.
  • Intriligator, M. D. (1975), "Strategic Considerations in the richardson Model of Arms races", The Journal of Political Economy, 83, 2: 339-354.
  • Jurado-Sánchez, j. y Jerez-Méndez, M. (2012): "Warfare, Economic Performance and the Struggle for World Hegemony in the Early Modern Period: Guns versus Butter in Eighteenth-Century Britain and Spain", Defence and Peace Economics, 23, 4: 389-412.
  • Kelleher, C.; Domke, W. y Eichenberg, r. (1980), "Guns, butter and growth: patterns of public expenditures in four western democracies, 1920-1975", en E. Fedder (ed.), Defense Politics of the Western Alliance, new York: Praeger, 153-188.
  • Kmenta, j. (1971), Elements of Econometrics, new York: Macmillan.
  • Kennedy, G. (1983), Defense Economics, new York: St. Martin's Press.
  • Lindgren, G. (1984), "Review Essay: Armaments and Economic Performance in Industrialized Market Economies", Journal of Peace Research, 21: 375-387.
  • Mcnair, E.; Murdoch, C. y Sandler, T. (1995), "Growth and Defense: Pooled Estimates for the NATO Alliance, 1951-1988", Southern Economic Journal, 61, 1: 846-860.
  • Mayer, T. (1986), "Arms races and War Initiation: Some Alternatives to the Intriligator-Brito Model", The Journal of Conflict Resolution, 35, 3: 443-473.
  • Mintz, A. (1989), "Guns vs Butter: A Disaggregated Analysis", American Political Science Review, 83, 4: 1285-1293.
  • Mintz, A. y Huang, Ch. (1990), "Defense Expenditures, Economic Growth, and the 'Peace Dividend'", American Political Science Review, 84, 4: 1283-1293.
  • Mintz, A. y Huang, Ch. (1991), "Guns versus Butter: The Indirect Link", American Journal of Political Science, 35, 3: 738-757.
  • Mok, J. W. y Duval, r. D. (1992), "Guns, Butter, and Debt: Balancing Spending Tradeoffs between Defense, Social Programs, and Budget Deficits", en A. Mintz (ed.), The Political Economy of Military Spending in the United States, New York and London: Routledge, 196-212.
  • Mosley, H. (1985), The Arms Race: Economic and Social Consequences, Lexington, MA: Lexington Books.
  • Murdoch, J. C. y Sandler, T. (1984), "Complementary, Free Riding, and the Military Expenditures of NATO Allies", Journal of Public Economics, 25, 1-2: 83-101.
  • Okamura, M. (1991), "Estimating the Impact of the Soviet Union's Threat on the United States-Japan Alliance: A Demand System Approach", The Review of Economics and Statistics, 73, 2: 200-207.
  • Peroff, K. (1976), "The Warfare-Welfare Tradeoff: Health, Public Aid, and Housing", Journal of Sociology and Social Welfare, 4: 366-381.
  • Peroff, K. y Podolak-Warren, M. (1979), "Does Spending on Defence Cut Spending on Health? A Time-Series Analysis of the U.S. Economy, 1929-1974", British Journal of Political Science, 9, 1: 21-39.
  • Pryor, F. L. (1968), Public Expenditures in Communist and Capitalist Nations, Londres: George Allen y Unwin LTD.
  • Ram, R. (1986), "Government Size and Economic Growth: A new Framework and Some Evidence from Cross-Section and Time-Series Data", American Economic Review, 76: 191-203.
  • Ram, R. (1995), "Defence expenditure and growth", en K. Hartley y T. Sandler (eds.), Handbook of Defense Economics, Amsterdam: Elsevier, 191-203.
  • Rasler, K. y Thompson, W. R. (1988), "Defense Burdens, Capital Formation, and Economic Growth", Journal of Conflict Resolution, 322: 61-86.
  • Richardson, L. F. (1960), Arms and Insecurity: a Mathematical Study of the Causes and Origins of War, Pittsburg, PA: Homewood.
  • Russett, B. M. (1969), "Who Pays for Defense?", American Political Science Review, 63, 2: 412-426.
  • Russett, B. M. (1970), What Price Vigilance? The Burdens of National Defense, New Haven: Yale University Press.
  • Russett, B. M. (1982), "Defense Expenditures and national Well-being", American Political Science Review, 76, 4: 767-777.
  • SIPRI (Stockholm International Peace research Institute) (varios años), Oxford: Oxford University Press.I
  • Smith, R. P. (1977), "Military expenditure and capitalism", Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1: 61-76.
  • Smith, R. P. (1980), "Military Expenditures and Investment in oECD Countries, 1954-1973", Journal of Comparative Economics, 4: 19-32.
  • Smith, R. P. y Georgiou, G. (1983), "Assessing the Effect of Military Expenditure on OECD Economics: A Survey", Arms Control, 4: 3-15.
  • Solow, R. M. (1988), Growth Theory: An Exposition, New York: Oxford University Press.
  • Szymansky, A. (1973), "Military spending and economic stagnation", American Journal of Sociology, 79: 1-14.
  • Wildavsky, A. (1964), The Politics of the Budgetary Process, Boston: Little, Brown and Company.
  • Wilensky, H. (1975), The welfare state and equality, Berkeley: university of California Press.
  • Zellner, A. (1962), "An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regression equations and tests for aggregation bias", Journal of the American Statistical Association, 57: 348-368.