Does a Clarke-Groves type tax prevent free riding when implementing Eurobonds?

  1. Carlos Contreras Gómez 1
  2. Julio Angulo
  1. 1 Applied Economics (Public Economics and Political Economy), Universidad Complutense de Madrid
Revista:
Applied economic analysis

ISSN: 2632-7627

Año de publicación: 2021

Volumen: 29

Número: 86

Páginas: 152-170

Tipo: Artículo

DOI: 10.1108/AEA-03-2020-0020 DIALNET GOOGLE SCHOLAR lock_openAcceso abierto editor

Otras publicaciones en: Applied economic analysis

Resumen

Purpose – The purpose of this paper is to propose a Clarke-Groves Tax (CGT) type as a remedy to the criticism that the implementation of Eurobonds has raised regarding the risk of undermining fiscal discipline. In this model, a government minimizes its sovereign debt-to-GDP ratio in a given period and decides whether to join a common sovereign debt club. In doing so, it exposes itself to a positive or negative tax burden while benefiting from the liquidity premium involved in creating a secure asset. The authors found that the introduction of this tax may prevent free riding behaviours if Eurobonds were to be implemented. To illustrate this, the authors provide some numerical simulations for the Eurozone. Design/methodology/approach – In the model presented, a government which optimizes a social utility function decides whether to join the common debt club. Findings – The adoption of the proposed tax could prevent free-riding behaviours and, therefore, encourages participation by those countries with lower debt levels that would have not otherwise taken part in this common debt mechanism. Under certain circumstances, we can expect the utility of all members of this club to improve. The bias in the distribution of gains might be mitigated by regulating the tax rule determining the magnitude of payment/reward. The proportion of the liquidity premium, arising from the implementation of a sovereign safe asset, has a decisive impact on the degree of the governments’ utility enhancement. Research limitations/implications – The adoption of a CGT would require Eurobonds club members to reach an agreement on “the” theoretical model for determining the sovereign debt yield. One of the limitations of this model is considering the debt-to-GDP ratio as the sole determinant of public debt yields. Moreover, the authors assumed the relationship between the debt-to-GDP ratio and funding costs to be identical for all countries. Any progress in the implementation of the proposed transfer scheme would require a more realistic and in-depth analysis. Practical implications – A new fiscal rule based on compensating countries with lower public debt levels could be a way to mitigate free-riding problems if a Eurobond mechanism is to be established. Originality/value – This fiscal rule has not been proposed or analysed before in a context such as that considered by this paper.

Referencias bibliográficas

  • Beber, A., Brandt, M.W. and Kavajecz, K.A. (2006), “Flight-To-Quality or Flight-To-Liquidity?
  • Evidence from the euro-area bond market”, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 12376.
  • Beck, T. Uhlig, H. and Wagner, W. (2011), “Insulating the financial sector from the European debt crisis: Eurobonds without public guarantees”,VoXEU. org, 17 CEPR’s Policy Portal.
  • Boonstra, W.W. (2005), “Towards a better stability pact”, Intereconomics, Vol. 40 No. 1, pp. 4-9.
  • Boonstra, W.W. (2011), “Can eurobonds solve EMU’s problems?”, Rabobank Economic Research DepartmentWorking Paper.
  • Brunnermeier, M.K. Garicano, L. Lane, P.R. Pagano, M. Reis, R. Santos, T. Van Nieuwerburgh, S. and Vayanos, D. (2012), “European safe bonds (ESBies)”,mimeo.
  • Bühler, W. and Trapp, M. (2009), “Time-varying credit risk and liquidity premia in bond and CDS markets”, Centre for Financial Research (CFR)Working Paper, 13. University of Cologne.
  • Clarke, E.H. (1971), “Multipart pricing of public goods”, Public Choice, Vol. 11 No. 1, pp. 17-33.
  • D’Aspremont, C. and Gerard-Varet, L. (1979), “Incentives and incomplete information”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 11, pp. 25-45.
  • Dajcman, S. (2012), “Comovement between stock and bond markets and the ‘flight-to-quality’ during financial market turmoil – a case of the eurozone countries most affected by the sovereign debt crisis of 2010–2011”,Applied Economics Letters, Vol. 19 No. 17, pp. 1655-1662.
  • De Grauwe, P. and Moesen, W. (2009), “Gains for all: a proposal for a common euro bond”, in Intereconomics, May/June, pp. 132 135.
  • Delpla, J. and vonWeizsäcker, J. (2010), “The blue bond proposal”, Bruegel Policy Brief, p. 3.
  • Du,W., Im, J. and Schreger, J. (2018), “The U.S. Treasury premium”, Journal of International Economics, Vol. 112, pp. 167-181.
  • Dübel, H.J. (2011), “Partial sovereign bond insurance by the eurozone: a more efficient alternative to blue (euro-) bonds”, CEPS Policy Brief, p. 252.
  • Economides, N. and Smith, R.C. (2011), “Trichet bonds to resolve the European sovereign debt problem”, Networks, Electronic Commerce, and Telecommunications (“NET”) Institute Working Paper, p. 1.
  • European Commission (2018a), “Proposal for a regulation of the European parliament and of the council on sovereign bond-backed securities”, COM 339 Final.
  • European Commission (2018b), “Commission staff working document impact assessment. An enabling regulatory framework for the development of sovereign bond-backed securities (SBBS)”, (Accompanying the document “Proposal for a Regulation of the European Parliament and of the Council on sovereign bond-backed securities”) SWD, 252 Final.
  • Favero, C. and Missale, A. (2010), “EU public debt management and eurobonds”, in Directorate General for Internal Policies Policy Department A: Economic and Scientific Policies Economic and Monetary Affairs, European Parliament, Brussels.
  • Gopal, M. and Pasche, M. (2012), “Market-based eurobonds without cross-subsidisation”, Working Papers on Global Financial Markets, 37.
  • Green, J. and Laffont, J.J. (1977a), “Characterization of satisfactory mechanisms for the revelation of preferences for public goods”, Econometrica, Vol. 45 No. 2, pp. 427-438.
  • Green, J. and Laffont, J.J. (1977b), “On the revelation of preferences for public goods”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 8 No. 1, pp. 79-93.
  • Gros, D. and Micossi, S. (2008), “A call for a European financial stability fund”, in The First Global Financial Crisis of the 21st Century Part II, in Felton, A. and Reinhart, C.M. (Eds), VoxEU.org Publication. Centre for Economic Policy Research (CEPR): 85-88.
  • Groves, T. (1973), “Incentives in teams”, Econometrica, Vol. 41 No. 4, pp. 617-631.
  • Groves, T. and Ledyard, J. (1977), “Optimal allocation of public goods: a solution to the free rider problem”, Econometrica, Vol. 45 No. 4, pp. 783-809.
  • Hellwig, C. and Philippon, T. (2011), “Eurobills, not eurobonds”, Voxeu.org, 2 CEPR’s Policy Portal, December.
  • Hellwig, M.F. (2003), “Public-good provision with many participants”, The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 70 No. 3, pp. 589-614.
  • Hild, A., Herz, B. and Bauer, C. (2012), “Structured eurobonds”, Universität Bayreuth Dicussion Paper, Vol. 7
  • IFO (2011), “What will eurobonds cost?”, Press release, 17 August.
  • Issing, O. (2009), “Why a common eurozone bond isn’t such a good idea”, White Paper Center for Financial Studies, 3. Frankfurt.
  • Kösters, W. (2009), “Common euro bonds no appropriate instrument”, in Intereconomics, May/June, 135-138.
  • Krishnamurthy, A. and Vissing-Jorgensen, A. (2012), “The aggregate demand for treasury debt”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 120 No. 2, pp. 233-267.
  • Liu, Y., Schmid, L. and Yaron, A. (2019), “The risks of safe assets”, Bank of Israel Conference. March.
  • Longstaff, F. (2003), “The flight-to-Liquidity premium”,The Journal of Business, Vol. 77 No. 3, pp. 511-526.
  • Mailath, G.J. and Postlewaite, A. (1990), “Asymmetric information bargaining problems with many agents”,The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 57 No. 3, pp. 351-367.
  • Mayer, T. (2009), “The case for a Europeanmonetary fund”, Intereconomics, May/June.
  • Nagel, S. (2016), “The liquidity premium of near-Money assets”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 131 No. 4, pp. 1927-1971.
  • Neeman, Z. (2004), “The relevance of private information in mechanism design”, Journal of Economic Theory, : Vol. 117 No. 1, pp. 55-77.
  • Tideman, T.N. and Tullock, G. (1976), “A new and superior process for making social choices”, Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 84 No. 6, pp. 1145-1159.
  • Tremonti, G. and Juncker, J.C. (2010), “E-bonds would end the crisis”,The Financial Times, Vol. 5.
  • Further reading Groves, T. and Loeb, M. (1975), “Incentives and public inputs”, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 4 No. 3, pp. 211-226.
  • Boonstra, W.W. (2010), “The creation of a common European bond market”, in Cahier Comte Boël, 14, ELEC, April.